Saturday, March 30, 2024

MEATY MATTERS: Co-op model not ideal for all

Avatar photo
Co-operatives emerged in the 19th century as an important business structure designed to protect the interests of a group of members, based on the principle of equitable distribution of benefits related to use or supply.
Reading Time: 3 minutes

The first New Zealand co-operative was formed in 1871 by eight cheese making settlers on the Otago Peninsula. By 1890 40% of dairy factories were co-operatives and by 1925 there were about 500, of which only three remained after the formation of Fonterra in 2001.

The co-operative model has continued to flourish throughout the world and in NZ and in 2017 the top 40 co-operatives represented 16% of this country’s GDP. 

Fonterra’s turnover outstripped the rest by a wide margin, its revenue equal to the combined turnover of the other companies making up the top 10. The rest of this group consisted of retail grocery groups Foodstuffs North and South Island, Zespri, Farmlands, Silver Fern Farms, Alliance, Southern Cross, Market Gardeners and Mitre 10, while next came fertiliser companies Ballance and Ravensdown then Westland Milk Products and Rabobank. 

That list gives a good idea of the industry types best suited to the co-operative model: agricultural production (dairy, meat and horticulture), agricultural inputs (fertiliser and farm supplies), financial services (health insurance and rural banking) and retail (grocery and hardware). From small beginnings, co-operatives have expanded to much larger groups of buyers and suppliers to take advantage of scale.

Recent trends suggest the dairy and red meat sectors supplier-based as distinct from purchaser-based co-operatives might struggle to realise that advantage because of highly capital-intensive operations, a failure to retain or generate sufficient capital for reinvestment, returning too high a proportion of the product margin to members and decisions to step outside their core business activity, which have ultimately proved to be an unwise use of scarce capital.

None of this contradicts the intended benefits of the co-operative model or the validity of its primary objective, which is to ensure an equitable distribution of profits to members based on use or supply. 

However, the problems facing Fonterra and Westland suggest the co-operative model might no longer be the best fit for the dairy industry, founded and conducted on co-operative principles for nearly 150 years. 

Equally, the red meat industry has experienced difficulties with Affco converting from a co-operative with no shareholder funds in 1994 to a listed then privately owned company, SFF having no option but to sell half the company to a Chinese investor and Alliance surviving as the only 100% co-operative though its return on assets remains disappointing.

The stronger performance of privately owned companies in both dairy and meat industries during the past decade, if not longer, has put further pressure on the co-operative side of the industry.

Lower or barely competitive product payments combined with the need to buy shares in a co-operative have made it attractive for suppliers to choose one of the growing number of private processors. 

Co-operatives work best for those farmers who have already shared up and farm in a region where the co-operative is the main or only option, particularly when a guarantee of processing capacity is critical.

Competition from newer, more efficient processors means there is a danger of the large co-operatives becoming processors of last resort, which then necessitates paying over the odds for livestock, as the only means of filling up available capacity. 

The exception to this is during drought or peak livestock flows, normally in the autumn and in the South Island, which might partly explain why lamb prices there are as much as 50 cents and prime beef 30 cents a kilo below North Island schedules. 

Milk payouts are a very obvious way of measuring processing and marketing gaps between dairy companies, which doesn’t provide very good reading for co-operatives Fonterra and, more particularly, Westland. 

The smaller Tatua traditionally makes a superior payout, which, clearly, has much to do with its relative size and specialised focus. 

However, dairy farmers have less flexibility than sheep and beef farmers in choosing their processor and have little option but to remain for a minimum of a season.

To my certain knowledge the meat industry paid too much for livestock throughout the 1990s and 2000s, relative to the market return, because of an excess of capacity. 

SFF’s attempt to extricate itself from low-end commodities and create added value was compromised by high debt, aging and inefficient capacity and procurement competition. 

The substantial investment by Shanghai Maling rescued the business and removed the crippling debt but the 2018 result provides no evidence of an improvement in operating performance. 

SFF and Alliance have closed capacity in recent years but the annual maintenance bill and capital expenditure needed to ensure the competitiveness of the remaining capacity remain substantial. 

Both companies have put great emphasis on moving up the value chain to try to capture a greater share of the final product price. But the cost of doing this, at the same time as spending scarce dollars on plant maintenance and upgrades, is significant.

In conclusion, it appears supplier-owned co-operatives might not be the best structure for large-scale commodity processing and international marketing.

There is an inherent tension between essential investment in operations, product development and brand development on the one hand and competitive payments to the shareholder suppliers on the other. 

Fonterra, Westland, Alliance and SFF have all found it tough to satisfy both priorities and two of these co-operatives have already chosen an outside investment solution.

Total
0
Shares
People are also reading